Eric Posner
Glen Weyl
Feudalism: heavy restraints on trade
Peasants are bonded tenants that rent land from landlords
Land used for inefficient, subsistence agriculture
Capitalism as "right to trade"
Industrial Revolution, Enclosure movement
Breakdown of feudal restrictions & obligations
A market for land develops
Peasant-tenants have little incentive to improve land
Most wealthy landlords inherited land and lazily collected their rents
Land ownership may be considered a monopoly
Landowner can hope to earn higher returns by holding out for a better offer to sell
Posner & Weyl: "the monopoly problem" is largely true of ownership in general (of any asset)
Estimate 25% loss of national output from monopoly problem
Adam Smith
1723-1790
"As soon as the land of any country has all become private property, the landlords, like all other men, love to reap where they never sowed, and demand a rent even for its natural produce. The wood of the forest, the grass of the field, and all the natural fruits of the earth, which, when land was in common, cost the labourer only the trouble of gathering them, come, even to him, to have an additional price fixed upon them. He must then pay for the licence to gather them; and must give up to the landlord a portion of what his labour either collects or produces. This portion, or, what comes to the same thing, the price of this portion, constitutes the rent of land," (Book I, Chapter XI)"
Smith, Adam, 1776, An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
Adam Smith
1723-1790
"The rent of land, therefore, considered as the price paid for the use of the land, is naturally a monopoly price. It is not at all proportioned to what the landlord may have laid out upon the improvement of the land, or to what he can afford to take; but to what the farmer can afford to give," (Book I, Chapter XI)"
Smith, Adam, 1776, An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
David Ricardo
1772-1823
"Thus by bringing successively land of a worse quality, or less favourably situated into cultivation, rent would rise on the land previously cultivated, and precisely in the same degree would profits fall; and if the smallness of profits do not check accumulation, there are hardly any limits to the rise of rent, and the fall of profit,"
Ricardo, David, 1815, Essay on the Influence of a Low Price of Corn on the Profits of Stock
David Ricardo
1772-1823
David Ricardo
1772-1823
Ultimately, marginal product of land would fall to 0 ⟹ economy in a permanent stationary state
This is the origin of Ricardian rent or economic rent (as in "rent-seeking")
William Stanley Jevons
1835-1882
"Property is only another name for monopoly."
Leon Walras
1834-1910
"Declaring individual land ownership [means] thwarting the beneficial effects of free competition by preventing the land from being used as is most advantageous for society."
"[By ending] individual landownership and monopolies [we can] suppress [the] true causes [of] feudality."
Leon Walras
1834-1910
Walras suggested "synthetic socialism"
Land owned by the government and rents it generates returned to public as a "social dividend" or put towards producing public goods
Hostile to central planning
"In the late nineteenth century, socialism was a rather amorphous term and was not always associated with central planning. Socialists agreed only on one point: that traditional private property and the inequality of its ownership posed significant challenges to prosperity, well-being, and political order," (p. 42).
Posner, Eric and E. Glen Weyl, 2017, Radical Markets
Henry George
1839-1897
"The nineteenth century saw an enormous increase in the ability to produce wealth. Steam and electricity, mechanization, specialization, and new business methods greatly increased the power of labor...Surely, these new powers would elevate society from its foundations, lifting the poorest above worry for the material needs of life...Yet we must now face facts we cannot mistake. All over the world we hear complaints of...labor condemned to involuntary idleness; capital going to waste...Where do we find the deepest poverty, the hardest struggle for existence, the greatest enforced idleness? Why, wherever material progress is most advanced...This relation of poverty to progress is the great question of our time."
George, Henry, 1879, Progress and Poverty (quoted in Posner and Weyl, 2017, pp.36-37)
Henry George
1839-1897
A "simpler, easier and quieter way" to solve the problem is to "appropriate land rent for public use, by taxation"
Land ("Gifts of nature") vs. "artifical capital" (human-made improvements)
Solution: allow private ownership in artificial capital, but abolish private ownership in land
Henry George
1839-1897
"Competitive common ownership"
Government owns all land, and leases it out to those it thinks make the most productive use of it
Individuals and businesses rent, but cannot own, land
Henry George
1839-1897
Modern (State and local) property taxes:
Versus George's land value tax:
Henry George
1839-1897
Occupants enjoy full value of improvements and structures built on land (privately owned)
Act as a tenant of the land (government is landlord), pay full rent value in taxes
People who can productively use land have high WTP the tax, those who would leave it idle would sell at low prices to avoid tax (no more absentee landlords)
Georgists often believed this "single tax" could replace all other taxes
"The Landlord's Game" created in 1902 to popularize Georgism
The famous Parker Brothers "Monopoly" board game based on this around 1930s (and interesting disputes about who invented it)
"The Landlord's Game" created in 1902 to popularize Georgism
The famous Parker Brothers "Monopoly" board game based on this around 1930s (and interesting disputes about who invented it)
Consider a market for a factor of production (inputs: land, labor, capital, etc.)
Recall market demand is the maximum willingness of firms to pay factor owners for use of the factor
Recall market supply is the minimum willingness of factor owners to accept, the minimum price necessary to bring a resource to market
But all (equivalent) factor units are paid the market price, p∗ determined by market factor supply and factor demand
Some factor owners would have accepted a job for less than p∗
Those owners earn economic rent in excess of what is needed to bring their factor into the market (its opportunity cost)
Consider a factor (such as land) for which the supply is perfectly inelastic (e.g. a fixed supply)
Then the entire value of the land is economic rent!
The less elastic the supply of a factor, the more economic rent it generates!
An increase in demand raises the price of the factor, and creates more economic rents
Think of land during the industrial revolution
A tax on land, τ, (if supply is perfectly inelastic) is not distortionary!
Gross price to buyers (rg) remains the same
Landowners bear the full economic incidence of he tax
No change in quantity, no Deadweight loss!
A tax on land, τ, (if supply is perfectly inelastic) is not distortionary!
Gross price to buyers (rg) remains the same
Landowners bear the full economic incidence of he tax
No change in quantity, no Deadweight loss!
In the limit, a 100% tax on land
Investment inefficiency: No incentive for occupants to invest in, or even care for, land they occupy
Tragedy of the commons: incentive to drain as much resources (minerals, vegetation, etc) from the land before it can be taxed
"We laid out a fancificul version of this approach...all property - every factory, house, and car - is held in common and the right to rent and use it is constantly auctioned. The citizen who offers the highest bid (in the form of a rental payment) possesses the object until outbid by another citizen. Each factory, house, or car would have a standing highest bid placedo n it, representing the rent that the current possessor agreed to pay to the government for using the asset. Anyone could beat this bid and claim the object. The money collected from rents is used to finance public goods...and fund a social dividend," (p.49).
1 Coase famously suggested this in 1959 in a famous article that contained the
seeds of the "Coase Theorem" before his famous 1960 paper.
Since 1994, Federal Communications Commission (FCC) auctions off electromagnetic spectrum licenses1
Problems: auctions are infrequent, winneres can (inefficiently) hold onto spectrum for decades
Continual auctions create investment inefficiency
If assets owned by the government (and only leased to user) then the higher bidder's bid goes to the government, not the current user
No incentive for user to invest to improve or maintain their assets
A tradeoff between allocative efficiency and investment efficiency
Use private property where investment efficiency more important
Use common ownership where allocative efficiency more important
U.S. mostly follows this scheme:
Forcing property into either private or common gets one form of inefficiency
Posner & Weyl: balance with "Partial Common Ownership" to preserve both incentives
Arnold Harberger
1924-
"If taxes are to be levied...on...the value of properties...it is important that assessment procedures be adopted which estimate the true economic value...The economist's answer...is simple and essentially fool-proof: allow each...owner...to declare the value of his property, make the declared values...public, and require that an owner sell his property to any bidder...willing to pay...the declared value. This system is simple, self-enforcing, allows no scope for corruption, has negligible cost of administration, and creates incentives, in addition to those already present in the market, for each property to be put to that use in which it has the highest economic productivity," (p.57).
Quoted in Posner, Eric and E. Glen Weyl, 2017, Radical Markets
Posner & Weyl: a "Common Ownership Self-Assessed Tax" (COST)
If tax is set approximately equal to the turnover rate, an owner wishing to change the self-assessed price of her asset:
Maximizes allocative efficiency
Recall: property rights as a bundle of sticks
Under COST, an owner is given right to use, and (partial) right to exclude
"We can conceptualize a COST as sharing ownership between society and the possessor. Possessors become lessees from society. Their lease terminates when a higher-value user appears, whereupon the lease is automatically transferred to that user," (p.72).
"Yet this is not central planning. The government does not set prices, allocate resources, or assign people jobs...[t]he government's role would become more limited than it is today because there would be no need for discretionary interventions, like eminent domain or public ownership of property in the conventional sense, to solve holdout and other monopoly-related problems. There would be much less need for distortionary and discretionary government taxes to raise revenue for the state. Furthermore, control of everything would be radically decentralized...Far from creating a form of centralized planning, the COST creates a new kind of market - a flexible market in uses, to replace the old market based on permanent ownership," (p.72).
"Every individual and business would have to list each of their possessions in a public register hosted on an online application and enter valuations for each item - or accept default valuations based on the original purchase price or on a database of prices of used goods (like today's Blue Book for used cars) - and would pay an annual tax based on the time-average price they listed over the course of the year. These lessees could change their valuations at any time...," (p.73).
"Anyone interested in acquiring ('posessing') a specific good would search the databased to find local items of interest. Barcode scanning or photographic recognition software would display the price of something in front of you. By clicking on the item, you transfer funds from your bank account into escrow, and the funds would then bee deposited to the current possessor's account on delivery of the asset. Nondelivery would be penalized as theft," (p.73).
"As we noted above, the economy underperforms by as much as 25% annually because of the misallocation of resources to low productivity firms. A fully implemented COST could increase social wealth by trillions of dollars every year. Moreover, a COST would raise substantial revenue. At the rate of roughly 7% annually that we imagine being near optimal, a COST would raise roughly 20% of national income. About half of that money would suffice to eliminate all existing taxes on capital, corporations, property, and inheritance, which economists agree are highly inefficient...[and] to wipe out the budget deficit and significantly reduce debt...
"The other half of COST revenue would be roughly $3,500 per person in the United States...and almost certainly would skyrocket...because of the more efficient allocation of assets...These funds could be used to finance government services, public goods...or social welfare programs for the poor. One could also imagine a system in which the revenue generated by the COST is simply sent back to the population on a per capita basis as a social dividend - akin to the universal basic income, which is currently being touted by leading commentators. In this form, a COST would also serve as a much more effective way to collect a tax on wealth...," (p.80).
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
Esc | Back to slideshow |